Economics for Physicists and Ecologists
Carmine Gorga
This article was originally published in
Transactions on Advanced Research, Vol.4 (1) 6-9, January 2008
REPRINTED WITH PERMISSION
Abstract: The
lack of communication among physicists, ecologists, and economists can be
mostly attributed to the type of mathematics economists use as well as their
study of flows of money rather than stocks of real wealth. This paper
presents the essential characteristics of a new framework of economic
analysis, Concordian economics, which uses standard mathematics and geometry
and observes stocks as well as flows of real and monetary wealth. This paper
thus attempts to build bridges among the relative disciplines, because it is
becoming increasingly clear that vexing problems of human and natural ecology
can be solved only through collaboration among economists, physicists, and
ecologists.
Keywords: economics, stocks, monetary wealth |
1. INTRODUCTION There is a well-known lack of communication among physicists, ecologists, and economists. Using a new framework of economic analysis, Concordian economics [1], a system of thought that results from the relentless application of age-old tools of logic and epistemology to mainstream economic theory, this paper attempts to b uild bridges among the various disciplines so that lines of communication can be opened and solutions can be found to today’s vexing problems of economics and e cology. Physicists, being practical problem solvers, and ecologists, being deeply concerned about the status quo, might join together in this mission to let economics r each the splendor of its full potential. 2. PROBLEM STATEMENT Lack of communication among physicists, ecologists, and economists is rooted in the practice of economists, who have developed their own specialized form of mathematics to analyze economic problems; and have reduced the number of admissible problems to those that exist in the market at the moment of the exchange. Thus they analyze only flows, not stocks of wealth; and they observe only money, not real resources. In particular, physicists have long remarked that modern economic theory cannot possibly be a fit description of the reality because, among other reasons, it is a closed system without inlets and outlets [2]. Ecologists, on their part, never seem to engage economists because, among other reasons, while they are mainly concerned with stocks of real wealth, economists are mainly concerned with flows of money [3]. 3. FINDINGS Three essential findings of Concordian economics are reported here with the assistance of modern mathematics and geometry: stocks are separated from flows of wealth; the real economy is separated from the monetary economy; these two parts of the economic process are then joined together through the introduction of the l egal and institutional economy into the equations. Through painstaking analysis (Gorga 2002, 23-158) [4], real wealth (RW) is defined as stocks of consumer g oods (CG), plus capital goods (KG) and goods hoarded (GH). The fundamental model of production (P) is formulated as follows (Ibid., 38, 313):
P = CG + KG + GH
IA = P
– GH
IA =
(CG + KG)
where IA = Investment Assets (until sold). Monetary wealth (MW) is defined as the sum of all financial instruments used to purchase CG, KG, and GH as well as other financial instruments: corresponding equations form the model of consumption (Ibid., 318). The legal economy is defined as the value of all rights of ownership o ver real anmonetary wealth: corresponding equations form the model of distribution (Ibid., 316). Since the structure of these models is selfsimilar, they are omitted here. The three systems of equations form an equivalence [5], the equivalence of production to distribution and to consumption. They describe the same entity, the economic process, from three strictly interconnected points of view. In more detail, this equivalence refers to the production of all real wealth; the distribution of ownership rights over both monetary and real wealth; and consumption (or expenditure) of monetary instruments to purchase real wealth. This equivalence can be more easily observed with the assistance of geometry. Thus, using established protocols, it is possible to synthesize the above three systems of equations into one unit represented by the following diagram: Figure 1 represents the economic process at the moment of the exchange—as in mainstream economics, but with an enlarged focus. The unit of account can be the economy of an individual person, an individual firm, the local, the national, or the world economy. Figure 1 reads as follows: When goods and services pass from producers to consumers, monetary instruments of a corresponding value pass from consumers to producers. For the exchange to occur, the transactors must be the owners of both money and real wealth. Then, one cycle of the economic process is completed. As can be seen, Concordian economics is wholly relational and inherently dynamic. This second characteristic becomes more explicit if one sees each rectangle of Figure 1 as a PoincarĂ© section. In Figure 1 the economic process is observed at one static moment in time.
There are three
approaches for a comprehensive study of the dynamics of the economic process.
One is the analytical/mathematical approach. It yields the following
generalized system of equations:
p. = fp(p,d,c)
d. = fd(p,d,c) c. = fc(p,d,c) where p. = rate of change in the production of real wealth, d. = rate of change in the pattern of distribution of ownership rights over real and monetary wealth, and c. = rate of change in the consumption or expenditure of monetary wealth. The second approach for the study of the dynamics of the economic process is the historical/latitudinal one. This study calls for following the dynamic transformation of the system, ideally from the beginning of time till today. Starting from flows of real and monetary wealth one obtains a result that is very familiar to modern physicists, a strange attractor or a Lorenz attractor, see, e.g., Thompson (1986, 228) [6]. A few cycles are reproduced here: With Figure 2, we are not only within the economic process—an area that is a black box to mainstream economics [7]; we have also found the inlets and outlets requested by physicists. The inlets are flows of real and monetary wealth; the outlets are consumer goods, goods hoarded, and money hoarded. It is only capital goods and money to purchase real wealth that remain permanently within the system. The flows of the legal/institutional economy are fully inserted in this construction: They are invisibly present at the moment of the exchange. In order to buy and sell wealth one has forever had to have ownership of that wealth. Indeed, to think of the extreme complexity of the reactions that occur within the economic system, the reader is encouraged to mentally close the two halves of Figure 2 thus creating the image of a torus or a cyclotron. In the reality of daily life, stocks and flows of real and monetary values do not organize themselves into neat patterns, but tend to intermingle and interact with each other. The third approach is the longitudinal/programmatic one, through which one obtains an external view of the economic system as a whole. This is a new perspective that yields a simplified understanding of other characteristics of the economic system. This mode of analysis can be briefly described as follows: If the economic system were composed of three identical, synchronous, and compenetrating spheres (obtained by rotating each rectangle of Figure 1 at ever increasing speed and in all directions about their geometric center), the system would leave behind only one trajectory as an indication of its dynamics. This line—whatever its pattern—would indicate that the three spheres were in continuous equilibrium with each other. This is not the case in economics: As Mandelbrot (1983, 1) [8] is fond of saying, "Clouds are not spheres, mountains are not cones, coastlines are not circles, and bark is not smooth, nor does lightning travel in straight lines." Can economic systems be expected to be represented by perfect solids?
To say the least, the
trajectory of aggregate values of monetary wealth (MW) can be expected to
soon leave the initial condition of equilibrium (0,0,0) and, spurred by the
facility with which monetary instruments can be produced, grow at a faster
rate than the trajectory of values of real wealth (RW). Also, the spheres
representing the pattern of distribution of values of ownership rights over
real and monetary wealth, which are known to remain rather static over time,
can be conflated into two overlapping straight lines to be identified as DO.
Then, over time, eliminating all short and long term, cyclical, random, or
aperiodic loops, breaks, and turns, the system as a whole can be expected to
leave behind idealized traces of motion as in the following figure:
Figure 3. Trajectories of the System as a Whole
The distance between RW and MW will eventually yield the mathematical measurement of the “bubble”. Current efforts to identify the bubble are especially intense [9]; physicists adept at chaos theory have been investigating this issue for quite some time [10]. Area "a"—with its alternative subareas a' and a''—attempts to describe the condition of disequilibrium (the bubble) that so often develops between monetary and real wealth and suggests that the smaller this area, the smaller the loss of real income over time. How to close the gap between the real and the monetary economy in the shortest possible time is clearly a problem of control, namely, a problem of economic policy—the problem of creating a just and sustainable economy. 4. CONCLUSION There is much work to be done. As can be seen, the intellectual framework is mostly done; it is the practical work that is all to be done. This is the work of organizing the data in accordance with the categories of thought specified above; this is the work of analyzing the data with the assistance of modern tools of scientific research. The tempi for the performance of this work can be enormously speeded up if physicists, ecologists, and economists assiduously work together [11]. REFERENCES [1] Gorga, C. (forthcoming), “Concordian economics: Tools to return relevance to economics,” Forum on Social Economics. [2] Nadeau, R. L., The Environmental Endgame: Mainstream Economics, Ecological Disaster, And Human Survival, Piscataway, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 2006. [3] Daly, H. E., Bouckaert, L., Opdebeeck, H., and Zsolnai, L., Frugality: Rebalancing Material and Spiritual Values in Economic Life, Oxford, Bern, Berlin, Bruxelles, Frankfurt am Main, New York, Wien: Peter Lang; pp. 207-226, 2008. [4] Gorga, C., The Economic Process: An Instantaneous Non-Newtonian Picture, University Press of America, Lanham, Md., and Oxford, 2002. [5] Gorga, C., “On the Equivalence of Matter to Energy and to Spirit,” Transactions on Advanced Research Vol. 3, N. 2: 40-45, 2007. [6] Thompson, J. M. T., Nonlinear Dynamics and Chaos, Geometric Methods for Engineers and Scientists, New York: Wiley, 1986. [7] Petrongolo, B., Pissarides, C. A., “Looking into the Black Box: A Survey of the Matching Function,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIX: 424, 2001. [8] Mandelbrot, B. B., The Fractal Geometry of Nature, New York: W. H. Freeman, 1983. [9] Because of its guidance from Ben Bernanke, most notable these days is the work done at the Bendheim Center for Finance at Princeton (Princeton Weekly Bulletin, May 26, 1997 and ff.). [10] See much work done at the Santa Fe Institute. [11] Matthews, E., The Weight of Nations: Material Outflows from Industrial Economies,Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute, 2000.
|